Forum
distribution:
Relying upon fund managers for enlightened use of concentrated voting
rights |
For earlier reports of concerns about
responsibilities created by concentration of fund manager control,
see
-
July 17, 2023,
Financial Times:
"BlackRock offers a vote to retail investors in its biggest ETF"
[Testing a strategy of letting fund customers assume responsibility for
proxy voting decisions]
-
June 18, 2022,
The Wall Street Journal: "The 70 BlackRock
Analysts Who Speak for Millions of Shareholders" [Increasing
marketplace concerns about intermediary concentration of other people's
voting power]
-
November 29, 2018, John C. Bogle, published in
The Wall Street
Journal: "Bogle Sounds a Warning on Index Funds" [Indexing
founder's views of need for responsible governance of proxy voting]
-
November 28, 2018, Lucian Bebchuk of Harvard Law School and Scott Hirst
of Boston University posting in The Harvard Law School Forum on
Corporate Governance and Financial Regulation: "Index Funds and the
Future of Corporate Governance: Theory, Evidence, and Policy"
[Academic analysis of concerns about concentrated control of
shareholder voting rights]
|
Source:
Bloomberg,
July 18, 2024, commentary
|
|
Maybe Good Governance Is Bad
**
** **
July 18, 2024 at 2:29 PM EDT
|
By Matt
Levine
Matt Levine is a Bloomberg
Opinion columnist. A former investment banker at
Goldman Sachs, he was a mergers and acquisitions
lawyer at Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz; a clerk for
the U.S. Court of Appeals for the 3rd Circuit; and an
editor of Dealbreaker.
|
|
Should index funds be illegal?
You know the theory:
When the same big diversified institutional investors own all of
the companies, those companies have less incentive to compete with
each other. If Airline A and Airline B have the same shareholders,
and Airline A cuts prices to win more market share, that simply
hurts the shareholders: Overall, the airlines sell the same number
of tickets but at lower prices.
We talk about
this theory a lot.
It is controversial, in part because of disputes about the
empirical evidence but mostly, I think, because it doesn’t feel right.
That is:
-
Most large diversified asset managers do
not think this way: They don’t want to reduce
competition, and they do not go around meeting with the
managers of their portfolio companies to say “hey you should
compete less.”
-
Most corporate executives do not think
this way: They don’t care about overall profits for their
shareholders; they care about their company’s profits
and market share. They care because they are naturally
competitive people who want to win, but they also care
because they are not diversified shareholders: The
executives themselves own a lot of stock in their own firms,
so they are motivated to win market share for themselves.
So if you think this
theory is right you will need sort of a better mechanism, one that
does not rely on the diversified investors actually wanting less
competition, or on the corporate managers trying to give it to
them.1
Here is a clever one from
Zohar Goshen and Doron Levit:
In equilibrium, common owners
exert market power indirectly by delegating control rights to
other shareholders through broad implementation of “strong”
governance structures across their portfolio firms. That is,
more firms adopt strong governance under common ownership.
These delegated control rights are then leveraged by
activists, which pressure managers of their target firms to
reduce investments. The aggregate effect of lower investments
reduces the demand for labor and lowers wages. Importantly,
even though activist hedge funds do not internalize
externalities across firms, the cumulative impact of their
interventions contributes to anticompetitive outcomes.
Effectively, common owners establish a labor market monopsony
without resorting to collusion among firms. Consequently, the
symbiotic relationship between common owners and hedge fund
activists is detrimental to society.
It is important to note that
common owners need not consciously act as a monopsony or a
cartel. The anticompetitive effects follow naturally from
common owners’ push for strong governance. The conventional
wisdom praises institutional investors for strengthening
corporate governance as it mitigates agency costs (Jensen and
Meckling 1976). And indeed, institutional investors are
consistently pushing toward strong governance structures for
publicly traded firms. However, this perspective often
overlooks the principal costs inflicted by activist hedge
funds. Consequently, common owners who push for strong
governance and bolster hedge fund activism, might mistakenly
attribute the realized positive returns on their portfolios to
the benefits of reduced agency costs rather than acknowledging
the role of labor monopsony at play. In other words, the
commonly held naive view that strong governance unequivocally
enhances shareholder value by reducing agency costs could
explain the anticompetitive impact of common ownership. .
|
They are concerned with
labor-market competition rather than product-market competition:
Their worry is not “companies with common owners won’t compete on
price” but rather “companies with common owners won’t compete to
hire workers.” But their mechanism is governance.
Schematically it is something like:
-
Big institutional investors like “good
governance.” They push companies to adopt good governance
structures that give shareholders strong rights to supervise
managers. Strong governance structures include things like one
share one vote (no dual-class stock), all directors elected
every year (no classified boards), independent board chairs,
no poison pills etc.
-
Good governance is good for activist
hedge funds: It’s hard to win an activist proxy fight at a
company with a staggered board and dual-class stock, but it’s
easier at a company with shareholder-friendly governance.
-
Activists, in this telling, are bad: They
“pressure managers of their target firms to reduce investments.”
There is a stereotype that activist investors push for short-term
financial engineering rather than long-term investments in the
business.
This, in Goshen and
Levit’s story, is bad for employees (fewer investments means less
demand for workers), but you could tell other stories: “Companies
with common owners are more vulnerable to activists, so they do
more stock buybacks and invest less in their business, so they
don’t compete as effectively to develop new products,” for
instance.
I don’t know. But what I
like about this story is that it does reflect how investors
and managers think:
-
Big diversified investors do care
about good governance. The giant asset managers who own every
company can’t necessarily develop strong views on how every
company should run its business; they focus on systemic
stewardship, on doing things that work across their
portfolio rather than things that are company-specific. And
they do tend to have a broad systematic view that strong,
shareholder-friendly governance is good, so all companies
should have it.
-
This story doesn’t rely on managers
wanting to reduce competition, or wanting to work in the
economic interests of their diversified shareholders. It
relies on managers being scared of activists, or being kicked
out after losing proxy fights.
* * *
1.
Except in the US shale oil industry, where it
is all
pretty straightforward.
View in article
This
column does not necessarily reflect the opinion of the editorial board
or Bloomberg LP and its owners.
To contact the author of this story: Matt Levine at mlevine51@bloomberg.net
©2024 Bloomberg L.P. All
Rights Reserved. |
|
|
|